Knowledge

Prebisch–Singer hypothesis

Source 📝

580:
For example, in 1800 an American worker could buy a candle that provided one hour of light for six hours of work. But in 1997 an American worker could buy an hour of light provided by a light bulb with barely half a second of work. That is to say, the invention of Edison improved by other North Americans managed to reduce the price drastically. Another case that we can see are personal computers that provide the service of calculations per second. Since the 1970s computers doubled their capacity of calculations per second every two years for the same amount of constant dollars. The fall in price is so rapid, that it has been necessary to invent new words because of the immense growth in the capacity of computers. First they were measured in bytes, then, kilobytes, megabytes, terabytes, yottabytes, etc ... Today's harvesters harvest many more hectares per hour than they did half a century ago, but they also have a geo-satellite system, combined with a chip that allows to improve productivity; plus air-conditioned, hermetic cabinets, which prevent dust intake and improve the quality of life of the operator, as well as radio and DVD player to improve his comfort. These examples suffice to show that if we correct the imports/exports price relationships by technological change, we will obtain a conclusion opposite to that of Prebisch–Singer. It is therefore argued that the peripheral countries that export commodities benefit from trade with the central powers to a greater extent than they do, because by incorporating the new technologies incorporated into manufactures they multiply their productivity. In fact, we can easily find examples of a reduction in the gap in GDP per capita between rich and poor countries when the latter open to free trade. Such is the case of Argentina and England between 1875 and 1930. Or China and USA between 1980 and 2018, or many other countries.
40: 616:
in favour of the 'investing' (i.e., developed) countries. However, Prebisch specifically deals with the economic cycle and highlights to a greater extent than Singer the reasons for the different behaviour of wages in developed and underdeveloped countries, and received much greater recognition for his work, in part because of efforts by industrialized countries like the United States to distance themselves from his work.
579:
Critics argue that it is not possible to compare the prices of manufactured goods over time because they change rapidly. The price relationship of Prebisch–Singer does not take into account technological change. The important thing is not the price of the goods but the service provided by said goods.
615:
Therefore, the statistical argument about the long-term trend in terms of trade of underdeveloped countries must be attributed to Singer. However, both seem to have independently invented similar explanations, stressing that the terms of trade moved against the 'borrowing' (i.e., underdeveloped) and
525:
Singer and Prebisch noticed a similar statistical pattern in long-run historical data on relative prices, but such regularity is consistent with a number of different explanations and policy stances. Later in his career, Prebisch argued that, due to the declining terms of trade primary producers
517:
interpretation of the international order which faults differences in power relations between 'core' and 'periphery' states as the chief cause for economic and political inequality (However, the Prebisch-Singer thesis also works with different bargaining positions of labour in developed and
536:. For this reason, much of the recent research focuses less on the relative prices of primary products and manufactured goods, and more on the relationship between the prices of simple manufactures produced by developing countries and of complex manufactures produced by advanced economies. 555:
sector could imply. They are warned to remember that the outlook for commodity prices is not favourable and that windfalls will tend to be temporary, with the subsequent relapse likely to be greater than the temporary windfall. This is exactly the warning which the PST would give.
600:, published a paper titled "Post-war Price Relations between Under-developed and Industrialized Countries", which suggested that the terms of trade of underdeveloped countries had declined significantly between 1876 and 1948. Inspired by this, 518:
developing countries). As a result, the hypothesis enjoyed a high degree of popularity in the 1960s and 1970s with neo-Marxist developmental economists and even provided a justification for an expansion of the role of the commodity
605: 532:
The hypothesis has lost some of its relevance in the last 30 years, as exports of simple manufactures have overtaken exports of primary commodities in most developing countries outside of
588:
Prebisch's lectures from 1945 to 1949 revealed the development of the theoretical strands of his argument. What he did not have was a statistical argument. In February 1949,
509:
This theory implies that the very structure of the global market is responsible for the persistent inequality within the world system. This provides an interesting twist on
499:
than primary products, especially food. Therefore, as incomes rise, the demand for manufactured goods increases more rapidly than demand for primary products.
431: 547:
to developing countries. They are warned to be prudent even when export prices are temporarily favourable and to guard against currency overvaluation and
931: 645: 471:
of primary-product-based economies to deteriorate. As of 2013, recent statistical studies have given support for the idea. The idea was developed by
326: 551:, with all the unfavourable impact on the rest of the economy and all the dangers of macroeconomic instability which a sudden boom in a major 593: 526:
face, developing countries should strive to diversify their economies and lessen dependence on primary commodity exports by developing their
778: 312: 424: 924: 576:(which exports mostly manufactured goods) saw deteriorating terms of trade—the opposite of what the hypothesis generally predicts. 712: 484: 417: 958: 543:
One indication of this is that the PST is now incorporated, both implicitly and explicitly, in the advice given by the
387: 298: 676:"Testing the Prebisch-Singer hypothesis since 1650: evidence from panel techniques that allow for multiple breaks" 132: 953: 866: 937:
Trade and Development Report Chapter 3: Evolution of the Terms of Trade and its Impact on Developing Countries
367: 290: 112: 963: 871: 805: 405: 23: 682: 496: 284: 544: 503: 457: 304: 707: 640: 630: 362: 31: 569: 527: 919: 220: 117: 834:
Joseph L. Love (1980). "Raul Prebisch and the Origins of the Doctrine of Unequal Exchange".
495:
A common explanation for this supposed phenomenon is that manufactured goods have a greater
675: 510: 357: 265: 94: 705: 8: 185: 84: 898: 843: 729: 190: 165: 74: 39: 765:
Bibi, Samuele (2024). Prebisch and the terms of trade. Resources Policy, 90, 104813.
753:
Bibi, Samuele (2024). Prebisch and the terms of trade. Resources Policy, 90, 104813.
480: 464: 372: 333: 200: 89: 79: 54: 902: 733: 888: 880: 721: 651: 519: 319: 180: 175: 170: 155: 122: 64: 59: 936: 766: 754: 601: 472: 352: 673: 506:, so a decline in their prices tends to reduce revenue rather than increase it. 791: 706:
David I. Harvey; Neil M. Kellard; Jakob B. Madsen; Mark E. Wohar (April 2010).
539:
In 1998, Singer argued that the thesis he pioneered has joined the mainstream:
468: 392: 245: 230: 215: 69: 884: 947: 625: 597: 548: 250: 240: 235: 195: 160: 725: 862: 260: 210: 635: 589: 514: 476: 377: 255: 205: 127: 893: 847: 606:
United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbeans
479:
in the late 1940s; since that time, it has served as a major pillar of
150: 674:
Rabah Arezki; Kaddour Hadri; Prakash Loungani; Yao Rao (August 2013).
573: 460: 445: 225: 572:, the terms of trade of most developing countries improved, while 560:
Recent statistical research has given the idea qualified support.
779:
The Terms of Trade Fifty Years Later - Convergence and Divergence
609: 552: 533: 867:"The origins and interpretation of the Prebisch-Singer thesis" 708:"The Prebisch–Singer hypothesis: four centuries of evidence" 925:
The Terms of Trade for Commodities in the Twentieth Century
604:
presented a paper of his own discussing the decline at the
860: 806:"LOS TÉRMINOS DE INTERCAMBIO Y EL CAMBIO TECNOLÓGICO" 932:United Nations Conference on Trade and Development 646:United Nations Conference on Trade and Development 945: 767:https://doi.org/10.1016/J.RESOURPOL.2024.104813 755:https://doi.org/10.1016/J.RESOURPOL.2024.104813 833: 803: 594:United Nations Department of Economic Affairs 425: 313:Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism 777:Singer, Hans (1998) The South Letter (30) " 432: 418: 892: 502:In addition, primary products have a low 946: 713:The Review of Economics and Statistics 485:import substitution industrialization 467:over the long term, which causes the 701: 699: 669: 667: 13: 922:, and Parra, María Angela. (2003) 792:Trade and Development Report, 2008 463:declines relative to the price of 14: 975: 696: 664: 388:Primitive accumulation of capital 913: 299:How Europe Underdeveloped Africa 38: 133:Uneven and combined development 854: 836:Latin American Economic Review 827: 797: 784: 771: 759: 747: 1: 657: 368:Global North and Global South 113:Ecologically unequal exchange 872:History of Political Economy 563: 7: 683:International Monetary Fund 619: 522:as a tool for development. 497:income elasticity of demand 456:) argues that the price of 285:The Accumulation of Capital 10: 980: 959:International trade theory 608:second annual meeting, in 583: 545:Bretton Woods Institutions 504:price elasticity of demand 450:Prebisch–Singer hypothesis 383:Prebisch–Singer hypothesis 885:10.1215/00182702-35-3-437 490: 726:10.1162/rest.2010.12184 641:Structuralist economics 631:Developmental economics 363:Illicit financial flows 790:United Nations (2008) 592:, then working in the 570:2000s commodities boom 558: 528:manufacturing industry 454:Prebisch–Singer thesis 954:Development economics 541: 483:and policies such as 221:Mirsaid Sultan-Galiev 920:Ocampo, José Antonio 804:Agustín Etchebarne. 358:Economic development 266:Immanuel Wallerstein 95:World-systems theory 964:Imperialism studies 186:John Bellamy Foster 85:Three Worlds Theory 32:Imperialism studies 16:Economic hypothesis 815:. pp. 159–195 465:manufactured goods 191:Andre Gunder Frank 166:Charles Bettelheim 75:Social imperialism 481:dependency theory 452:(also called the 442: 441: 373:Lumpenbourgeoisie 334:Naked Imperialism 201:Rudolf Hilferding 118:North–South model 90:Ultra-imperialism 80:Super-imperialism 55:Dependency theory 971: 907: 906: 896: 858: 852: 851: 831: 825: 824: 822: 820: 810: 801: 795: 788: 782: 775: 769: 763: 757: 751: 745: 744: 742: 740: 703: 694: 693: 691: 689: 680: 671: 652:Unequal exchange 520:futures exchange 434: 427: 420: 320:Monopoly Capital 181:Arghiri Emmanuel 176:Nikolai Bukharin 156:Giovanni Arrighi 123:Unequal exchange 65:Neo-Gramscianism 60:Intercommunalism 42: 19: 18: 979: 978: 974: 973: 972: 970: 969: 968: 944: 943: 916: 911: 910: 859: 855: 832: 828: 818: 816: 808: 802: 798: 789: 785: 776: 772: 764: 760: 752: 748: 738: 736: 704: 697: 687: 685: 678: 672: 665: 660: 622: 586: 566: 493: 438: 398: 397: 353:Banana republic 348: 340: 339: 279: 271: 270: 146: 138: 137: 108: 100: 99: 50: 17: 12: 11: 5: 977: 967: 966: 961: 956: 942: 941: 929: 915: 912: 909: 908: 879:(3): 437–467. 853: 826: 796: 783: 770: 758: 746: 720:(2): 367–377. 695: 662: 661: 659: 656: 655: 654: 649: 643: 638: 633: 628: 621: 618: 585: 582: 565: 562: 492: 489: 469:terms of trade 440: 439: 437: 436: 429: 422: 414: 411: 410: 409: 408: 400: 399: 396: 395: 393:Third worldism 390: 385: 380: 375: 370: 365: 360: 355: 349: 346: 345: 342: 341: 338: 337: 330: 323: 316: 309: 302: 295: 288: 280: 277: 276: 273: 272: 269: 268: 263: 258: 253: 248: 246:Huey P. Newton 243: 238: 233: 231:Rosa Luxemburg 228: 223: 218: 216:Vladimir Lenin 213: 208: 203: 198: 193: 188: 183: 178: 173: 168: 163: 158: 153: 147: 144: 143: 140: 139: 136: 135: 130: 125: 120: 115: 109: 106: 105: 102: 101: 98: 97: 92: 87: 82: 77: 72: 70:Neocolonialism 67: 62: 57: 51: 48: 47: 44: 43: 35: 34: 28: 27: 15: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 976: 965: 962: 960: 957: 955: 952: 951: 949: 939: 938: 933: 930: 927: 926: 921: 918: 917: 914:Other sources 904: 900: 895: 890: 886: 882: 878: 874: 873: 868: 864: 857: 849: 845: 841: 837: 830: 814: 813:Eseade.edu.ar 807: 800: 793: 787: 780: 774: 768: 762: 756: 750: 735: 731: 727: 723: 719: 715: 714: 709: 702: 700: 684: 677: 670: 668: 663: 653: 650: 647: 644: 642: 639: 637: 634: 632: 629: 627: 626:Celso Furtado 624: 623: 617: 613: 612:in May 1949. 611: 607: 603: 602:Raúl Prebisch 599: 598:New York City 595: 591: 581: 577: 575: 571: 561: 557: 554: 550: 549:Dutch Disease 546: 540: 537: 535: 530: 529: 523: 521: 516: 512: 507: 505: 500: 498: 488: 486: 482: 478: 474: 473:Raúl Prebisch 470: 466: 462: 459: 455: 451: 447: 435: 430: 428: 423: 421: 416: 415: 413: 412: 407: 404: 403: 402: 401: 394: 391: 389: 386: 384: 381: 379: 376: 374: 371: 369: 366: 364: 361: 359: 356: 354: 351: 350: 344: 343: 336: 335: 331: 329: 328: 324: 322: 321: 317: 315: 314: 310: 308: 307: 303: 301: 300: 296: 294: 293: 289: 287: 286: 282: 281: 275: 274: 267: 264: 262: 259: 257: 254: 252: 251:Walter Rodney 249: 247: 244: 242: 241:Kwame Nkrumah 239: 237: 236:Antonio Negri 234: 232: 229: 227: 224: 222: 219: 217: 214: 212: 209: 207: 204: 202: 199: 197: 196:Michael Hardt 194: 192: 189: 187: 184: 182: 179: 177: 174: 172: 169: 167: 164: 162: 161:Paul A. Baran 159: 157: 154: 152: 149: 148: 142: 141: 134: 131: 129: 126: 124: 121: 119: 116: 114: 111: 110: 104: 103: 96: 93: 91: 88: 86: 83: 81: 78: 76: 73: 71: 68: 66: 63: 61: 58: 56: 53: 52: 46: 45: 41: 37: 36: 33: 30: 29: 25: 21: 20: 935: 923: 876: 870: 863:Richard Toye 856: 842:(3): 45–72. 839: 835: 829: 817:. Retrieved 812: 799: 786: 773: 761: 749: 737:. Retrieved 717: 711: 686:. Retrieved 614: 587: 578: 567: 559: 542: 538: 531: 524: 508: 501: 494: 453: 449: 443: 382: 332: 325: 318: 311: 305: 297: 291: 283: 261:Leon Trotsky 211:J. A. Hobson 894:10036/25832 861:John Toye; 636:Group of 77 590:Hans Singer 568:During the 515:neo-Marxist 511:Wallerstein 477:Hans Singer 461:commodities 378:Neo-Marxism 306:Imperialism 256:Paul Sweezy 206:Peter Gowan 171:Ľuboš Blaha 128:Superprofit 948:Categories 819:3 February 739:30 October 688:30 October 658:References 151:Samir Amin 574:east Asia 564:Criticism 446:economics 327:Multitude 903:28151403 865:(2003). 734:57569448 648:(UNCTAD) 620:See also 406:Category 226:Li Minqi 107:Concepts 49:Theories 24:a series 22:Part of 934:(2005) 848:2502991 584:History 487:(ISI). 458:primary 347:Related 901:  846:  732:  610:Havana 553:export 534:Africa 491:Theory 448:, the 292:Empire 145:People 899:S2CID 844:JSTOR 809:(PDF) 730:S2CID 679:(PDF) 278:Works 26:about 821:2019 741:2014 690:2014 475:and 889:hdl 881:doi 722:doi 596:in 513:'s 444:In 950:: 897:. 887:. 877:35 875:. 869:. 840:15 838:. 811:. 728:. 718:92 716:. 710:. 698:^ 681:. 666:^ 940:. 928:. 905:. 891:: 883:: 850:. 823:. 794:. 781:" 743:. 724:: 692:. 433:e 426:t 419:v

Index

a series
Imperialism studies

Dependency theory
Intercommunalism
Neo-Gramscianism
Neocolonialism
Social imperialism
Super-imperialism
Three Worlds Theory
Ultra-imperialism
World-systems theory
Ecologically unequal exchange
North–South model
Unequal exchange
Superprofit
Uneven and combined development
Samir Amin
Giovanni Arrighi
Paul A. Baran
Charles Bettelheim
Ľuboš Blaha
Nikolai Bukharin
Arghiri Emmanuel
John Bellamy Foster
Andre Gunder Frank
Michael Hardt
Rudolf Hilferding
Peter Gowan
J. A. Hobson

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.